interest rate question

If coutry A has a higher interest rate than country B, keep other elements constant ideally,will the currency in A appreciate relative to B or the other way around? I have two theories here:
According to the interest rate parity, it seems that B's currency will appreciate against A.
However, if A has a higher interest rate, money tends to flux into A because it will give back more interest, right? And so it will push up the demand for currency A, which should rise.
Both theories seems to make sense to me... I am confused which one should be right then...Can someone explain it?

 
Martinghoul:
How do you arrive at the former conclusion (that B's ccy will appreciate vs A's) from interest rate parity?
Ye, as Tempaccount said, the currency with the higher interest rate is expected to depreciate in order to satisfy the no-arbitrage condition, which is the interest rate parity.
 
hzsh2009:
Martinghoul:
How do you arrive at the former conclusion (that B's ccy will appreciate vs A's) from interest rate parity?
Ye, as Tempaccount said, the currency with the higher interest rate is expected to depreciate in order to satisfy the no-arbitrage condition, which is the interest rate parity.
I think you're thinking about it somewhat incorrectly... The "risk-neutral" world and the "real" world are different.
 

Both are correct (in theory), but the difference is one of time horizon as well as theory vs. practice.

In the short term and in practice after a rate announcement, higher interest rates encourage capital inflows, which drives the currency higher.

If you look at the pricing of any forward contract, the currency with the higher interest rate is expected to depreciate in order to satisfy the no-arbitrage condition. In other words, covered interest rate parity generally holds, because no bank is going to just give you the interest rate of the higher yielding currency without making you accept the exchange risk.

The theory of interest rate parity says that there would be an uncovered arbitrage if that higher yielding currency did not depreciate. Over a very long time horizon, that's probably true, but other factors besides interest rates affect the value of currencies in the meantime.

The mechanism by which a no-arbitrage condition is satisfied is arbitrage, meaning the theory assumes that speculators will buy the lower yielding currency because returns on cash should equalize. There are a few reasons this may not happen - arbitrage has limitations. Capital may not move freely between the two countries, and there may be persistent differences in the risk-return profile of each country's assets that justify a difference in rates. In a nutshell, that is why uncovered interest arbitrage is possible - sometimes (often, actually), the currency with the higher interest rate also has higher risk-adjusted return potential.

The way I like to think about this dynamic, and this is kind of my own theory, is that the short-term impact of a change in rates sets up the long-term arbitrage opportunity. This is related to Dornbusch's overshooting hypothesis, which you should read if you're interested in learning more about rates. Consider a thought experiment: two countries have perfectly equivalent economies, 0% interest rates, and a 1:1 exchange rate. All of a sudden, country A increases its interest rate to 5%. In the short term, the exchange rate appreciates in favor of country A as speculators move capital from country B to country A. All else equal, I would expect the exchange rate (expressed in number of units of A's currency one unit of B's currency is worth) to move to 1/1.05 = 0.95238. The one-year forward rate would be 1.0000, however. Why? Given perfect capital mobility and uncovered interest rate parity, that would set up a 5% yield on the now fundamentally undervalued currency B, to match the 5% yield in currency A. In practice it's never this neat, but that's the idea.

 
tempaccount:
Both are correct (in theory), but the difference is one of time horizon as well as theory vs. practice.

In the short term and in practice after a rate announcement, higher interest rates encourage capital inflows, which drives the currency higher.

If you look at the pricing of any forward contract, the currency with the higher interest rate is expected to depreciate in order to satisfy the no-arbitrage condition. In other words, covered interest rate parity generally holds, because no bank is going to just give you the interest rate of the higher yielding currency without making you accept the exchange risk.

The theory of interest rate parity says that there would be an uncovered arbitrage if that higher yielding currency did not depreciate. Over a very long time horizon, that's probably true, but other factors besides interest rates affect the value of currencies in the meantime.

The mechanism by which a no-arbitrage condition is satisfied is arbitrage, meaning the theory assumes that speculators will buy the lower yielding currency because returns on cash should equalize. There are a few reasons this may not happen - arbitrage has limitations. Capital may not move freely between the two countries, and there may be persistent differences in the risk-return profile of each country's assets that justify a difference in rates. In a nutshell, that is why uncovered interest arbitrage is possible - sometimes (often, actually), the currency with the higher interest rate also has higher risk-adjusted return potential.

The way I like to think about this dynamic, and this is kind of my own theory, is that the short-term impact of a change in rates sets up the long-term arbitrage opportunity. This is related to Dornbusch's overshooting hypothesis, which you should read if you're interested in learning more about rates. Consider a thought experiment: two countries have perfectly equivalent economies, 0% interest rates, and a 1:1 exchange rate. All of a sudden, country A increases its interest rate to 5%. In the short term, the exchange rate appreciates in favor of country A as speculators move capital from country B to country A. All else equal, I would expect the exchange rate (expressed in number of units of A's currency one unit of B's currency is worth) to move to 1/1.05 = 0.95238. The one-year forward rate would be 1.0000, however. Why? Given perfect capital mobility and uncovered interest rate parity, that would set up a 5% yield on the now fundamentally undervalued currency B, to match the 5% yield in currency A. In practice it's never this neat, but that's the idea.

Great! This is exactly what I was wondering about!! I read somewhere else about the long term and short term effects but it wasnt very clear. Your explaination is much much better. Thank you! I understand that real life circumstances are different from this interest rate parity theory, it's just that the completely opporsite of my two assumptions bothers me. Now I fully understand the reason. Again, thank you so much for the help! Your own theory makes great sense,I really appreciate it!

 
tempaccount:

Both are correct (in theory), but the difference is one of time horizon as well as theory vs. practice.

In the short term and in practice after a rate announcement, higher interest rates encourage capital inflows, which drives the currency higher.

If you look at the pricing of any forward contract, the currency with the higher interest rate is expected to depreciate in order to satisfy the no-arbitrage condition. In other words, *covered* interest rate parity generally holds, because no bank is going to just give you the interest rate of the higher yielding currency without making you accept the exchange risk.

The theory of interest rate parity says that there would be an *uncovered* arbitrage if that higher yielding currency did not depreciate. Over a very long time horizon, that's probably true, but other factors besides interest rates affect the value of currencies in the meantime.

The mechanism by which a no-arbitrage condition is satisfied is arbitrage, meaning the theory assumes that speculators will buy the lower yielding currency because returns on cash should equalize. There are a few reasons this may not happen - arbitrage has limitations. Capital may not move freely between the two countries, and there may be persistent differences in the risk-return profile of each country's assets that justify a difference in rates. In a nutshell, that is why uncovered interest arbitrage is possible - sometimes (often, actually), the currency with the higher interest rate also has higher risk-adjusted return potential.

The way I like to think about this dynamic, and this is kind of my own theory, is that the short-term impact of a change in rates sets up the long-term arbitrage opportunity. This is related to Dornbusch's overshooting hypothesis, which you should read if you're interested in learning more about rates. Consider a thought experiment: two countries have perfectly equivalent economies, 0% interest rates, and a 1:1 exchange rate. All of a sudden, country A increases its interest rate to 5%. In the short term, the exchange rate appreciates in favor of country A as speculators move capital from country B to country A. All else equal, I would expect the exchange rate (expressed in number of units of A's currency one unit of B's currency is worth) to move to 1/1.05 = 0.95238. The one-year forward rate would be 1.0000, however. Why? Given perfect capital mobility and uncovered interest rate parity, that would set up a 5% yield on the now fundamentally undervalued currency B, to match the 5% yield in currency A. In practice it's never this neat, but that's the idea.

Wow, this is a great explanation. Short term money would flow into Country A, appreciating its currency. I could now get more of Country B currency for 1 dollar of Currency A due to the appreciation. Based on your calculation it should be 5% more, if it was more I could convert to B and gain a higher yield than the 5% interest rate in Country A, if it were less the opposite would happen (pocketing the difference between the interest rate and the exchange rate).

But why would the forward contract depreciate? Because its assuming that that at delivery the currency depreciation would equal the impact of the change in interest rate? I guess the opportunity here would be to speculate as to whether the movements in the exchange rate would happen before the delivery date.

This macro stuff is fascinating. There is still a part of me that would love to explore macro investing. As a value investor its tough to have such fluid, dynamic thesis that aren't derived on any concrete fundamental values for long. But I still think back to my university days when the genius of Soros & Druckenmiller inspired me to move into economics.

Great post again.

 
Best Response
blackthorne:
But why would the forward contract depreciate? Because its assuming that that at delivery the currency depreciation would equal the impact of the change in interest rate? I guess the opportunity here would be to speculate as to whether the movements in the exchange rate would happen before the delivery date.

Thanks, glad you liked it. Yes, if you don't think the forward price is right you can still speculate, you don't have to hedge in the spot market. But the bank writing the contract generally will.

The reason the forward price of B is higher (i.e. B appreciates from 0.95 to 1.0 or A depreciates from 1.05 to 1.0, round numbers) is because the seller of the forward contract can hedge by buying the foreign currency A in the spot market. They earn the 5% yield in country A. If this didn't hold there would be an arbitrage opportunity - for example, if the forward rate in the higher-yielding currency were equal to the spot rate, you could borrow in the lower-yielding currency to buy spot and sell it back 1-year forward. You'd capture the interest rate differential without any exchange risk. In my example above, it'd be like borrowing at 0% and earning 5% interest! (Like a teaser rate on a credit card - not that long ago when checking accounts had better rates people used to do this with credit cards!).

This is all ignoring trading frictions (commissions, borrow costs, bid/ask spreads) that may make it seem like there's an opportunity in the forward market where there really isn't.

 

Ut qui commodi dolore facilis molestiae voluptatum. Quam consequatur praesentium exercitationem aliquid. Earum et rem et qui mollitia. Natus sunt consequatur numquam omnis nobis maiores.

Commodi quisquam aut quam quo voluptatum. Quisquam quaerat aliquid mollitia rem assumenda et enim dolore. Dolor a facere ratione placeat rem eveniet id. Omnis voluptas nobis tempora voluptas voluptatem deserunt.

Career Advancement Opportunities

April 2024 Hedge Fund

  • Point72 98.9%
  • D.E. Shaw 97.9%
  • Citadel Investment Group 96.8%
  • Magnetar Capital 95.8%
  • AQR Capital Management 94.7%

Overall Employee Satisfaction

April 2024 Hedge Fund

  • Magnetar Capital 98.9%
  • D.E. Shaw 97.8%
  • Blackstone Group 96.8%
  • Two Sigma Investments 95.7%
  • Citadel Investment Group 94.6%

Professional Growth Opportunities

April 2024 Hedge Fund

  • AQR Capital Management 99.0%
  • Point72 97.9%
  • D.E. Shaw 96.9%
  • Magnetar Capital 95.8%
  • Citadel Investment Group 94.8%

Total Avg Compensation

April 2024 Hedge Fund

  • Portfolio Manager (9) $1,648
  • Vice President (23) $474
  • Director/MD (12) $423
  • NA (6) $322
  • 3rd+ Year Associate (24) $287
  • Manager (4) $282
  • Engineer/Quant (71) $274
  • 2nd Year Associate (30) $251
  • 1st Year Associate (73) $190
  • Analysts (225) $179
  • Intern/Summer Associate (22) $131
  • Junior Trader (5) $102
  • Intern/Summer Analyst (250) $85
notes
16 IB Interviews Notes

“... there’s no excuse to not take advantage of the resources out there available to you. Best value for your $ are the...”

Leaderboard

1
redever's picture
redever
99.2
2
BankonBanking's picture
BankonBanking
99.0
3
Betsy Massar's picture
Betsy Massar
99.0
4
Secyh62's picture
Secyh62
99.0
5
GameTheory's picture
GameTheory
98.9
6
CompBanker's picture
CompBanker
98.9
7
dosk17's picture
dosk17
98.9
8
kanon's picture
kanon
98.9
9
DrApeman's picture
DrApeman
98.8
10
Linda Abraham's picture
Linda Abraham
98.8
success
From 10 rejections to 1 dream investment banking internship

“... I believe it was the single biggest reason why I ended up with an offer...”