Trade Efficiency Rule

 A phenomenon that occurs when all producers in a global market focus only on making a single good. 

Author: Sid Arora
Sid Arora
Sid Arora
Investment Banking | Hedge Fund | Private Equity

Currently an investment analyst focused on the TMT sector at 1818 Partners (a New York Based Hedge Fund), Sid previously worked in private equity at BV Investment Partners and BBH Capital Partners and prior to that in investment banking at UBS.

Sid holds a BS from The Tepper School of Business at Carnegie Mellon.

Reviewed By: Kevin Henderson
Kevin Henderson
Kevin Henderson
Private Equity | Corporate Finance

Kevin is currently the Head of Execution and a Vice President at Ion Pacific, a merchant bank and asset manager based Hong Kong that invests in the technology sector globally. Prior to joining Ion Pacific, Kevin was a Vice President at Accordion Partners, a consulting firm that works with management teams at portfolio companies of leading private equity firms.

Previously, he was an Associate in the Power, Energy, and Infrastructure Investment Banking group at Lazard in New York where he completed numerous M&A transactions and advised corporate clients on a range of financial and strategic issues. Kevin began his career in corporate finance roles at Enbridge Inc. in Canada. During his time at Enbridge Kevin worked across the finance function gaining experience in treasury, corporate planning, and investor relations.

Kevin holds an MBA from Harvard Business School, a Bachelor of Commerce Degree from Queen's University and is a CFA Charterholder.

Last Updated:December 11, 2023

What is the Trade Efficiency Rule?

The trade efficiency rule is a phenomenon that occurs when all producers in a global market focus only on making a single good. Such an economic paradigm gives rise to the trade efficiency rule. 

The rationale for this regulation is that specialization will allow producers to "expertly" create a particular item at a lower cost than would be possible for a non-specialized producer. Because manufacturers may now charge less while still making a profit, the price of the item will fall. 

One country would specialize in manufacturing each vital good in a perfect global economy. As a result, the cost to make items throughout the economy would fall, making them more accessible to more people. 

The efficiency of Vietnam's exports with its key trade partners is estimated using a stochastic gravity model in this research. The efficiency of exports is measured as the proportion of actual shipments to the potential export volume. 

Additionally, the paper examines the effect that FTAs and rules of origin had on the productivity of Vietnam's exports to its key trade partners from 1995 to 2013. 

The empirical findings indicate that Vietnam's actual export volume is much lower than the predicted efficient level, meaning substantial space for growing exports. 

However, the country's lack of participation in the European Union and the North American Free Trading Agreement (NAFTA) reduced its trade efficiency. 

These results suggest that Vietnam should join more free trade agreements (FTAs) with trading partners and adopt more flexible rules.

Also, the country's trade efficiency can be significantly improved by attracting export-oriented FDIs and adjusting the export mix. 

An international economy based on the Trade Efficiency Rule may seem appealing to shoppers, but it has certain drawbacks. A monopoly occurs when a single manufacturer dominates the market for a specific item or service. 

It's inevitable that once a country becomes unbeatable in price, other countries will stop trying to compete with it and instead focus on creating something else. 

Consequently, fewer firms will compete, giving one country a disproportionate amount of market sway. 

On the other hand, modern economies generate various commodities and may compete in several sectors simultaneously. Therefore the chance of such a phenomenon occurring in practice is meager.

How can the Trade Efficiency Rule be Measured?

If we examine a country's production-possibilities border, we may understand how strictly it adheres to the trade efficiency rule concerning a specific good. 

Particularly with the labor force and available capital limitations, a country's production-possibilities frontier will reveal how many of a given item it can create. 

Specifically, the items at which a country excels relative to others will be determined by the incline of its production-possibilities border. First, let's say that countries A and B have the same quantity of labor and capital. 

Let's say that both countries solely manufacture apples and oranges. Then, if we examine the border of possible output for Country A, we find that it excels in apple production. 

If Country A were to put all of its money and people into making apples, we'd see that it could make a thousand of them. 

If all of Nation B's money and workforce were put into apple production, the production-possibilities frontier would show that just 500 apple units could be created. 

Orange Producing Nation B is much more advanced than Orange Producing Nation A. 

If Country B were to focus all of its resources on orange production, we could predict that it would be able to generate 1,000 oranges. 

If all of Nation A's wealth and workforce were put toward producing oranges, the production-possibilities frontier would reveal that just 500 oranges could be made. 

According to the Trade Efficiency Rule, in this case: 

  • Country A should focus only on apple production, and Country B should concentrate primarily on orange production. As a result, prices for both items will be pushed down as production levels increase. 
  • Both countries may eventually benefit from fine-tuning their manufacturing systems to increase efficiency and decrease costs. Trade restrictions involving services are more nuanced than those involving products. 
  • Tariffs are the standard means through which international commerce is regulated. You can quantify their impact on the cost of imported items by looking at the tariff rate. On the other hand, governmental regulation is often used to limit service commerce. 

These rules can potentially increase the cost or price of services provided by international and local providers since they impact the entrance and operations.

Competitive Markets

When market efficiency is low, it is useless to look at pricing history to anticipate how the market will behave. If all relevant information is included in current pricing, then there is no need to look to historical data for insight into the future. 

Consequently, future price shifts can only result from newly accessible knowledge. 

  1. This hypothesis suggests that investors should put less faith in momentum investing or other techniques that rely on technical analysis to make trading or investment choices. 
  2. This hypothesis version allows for the potential that fundamental analysis might provide excess returns. This idea, formerly dogmatically embraced, is still taught extensively in academic finance studies but with less vigor than in the past. 
  3. The firm, semi-strong, and weak forms of the EMH represent the spectrum of opinions held by investors and academics on the market's real efficiency. Strong form efficiency proponents are often passive index investors that agree with Fame. 
  4. Active trading may provide anomalous gains via arbitrage, according to proponents of the weak form of the EMH, whereas practitioners of the semi-strong version fall in the center.
  5. To contrast the views of Fame and his supporters, value investors think equities might be undervalued (priced at a discount to their actual value). 
  6. Successful value investors earn money by buying companies at a discount undervalued and selling them when their market price reflects or exceeds their actual value. 
  7. Active traders are sometimes cited as evidence against the existence of a perfectly efficient market. No one would be motivated to become an active trader if they couldn't make money by outperforming the market. 
  8. Furthermore, because the EMH requires minimal transaction costs for markets to function efficiently, the fees imposed by active managers prove that the EMH is false.

Trade Efficiency Rule Background

One of the first areas of study in economics is the study of international commerce and commercial policy. 

Government officials, academics, and economists have, from the time of the ancient Greeks to the present day, sought to figure out what factors lead to commerce between nations, whether trade is beneficial or detrimental, and what trade policy is ideal for each given country. 

There has always been a two-sided perspective on trade, dating back to ancient Greek philosophers. On the one hand, people see the obvious advantages of globalization but also worry that certain local businesses (or workers or cultures) would suffer. 

Various scholars have reached different findings on the desirability of having free trade depending on the weights placed on the overall advantages of work vs. the losses of individuals disadvantaged by imports. 

However, economists have compared free trade to technical advancement: it may hurt special interests but provides enormous societal advantages. 

The difficulties inherent in this dual perspective on trade have never been resolved, as seen by the heated arguments about trade today.

"Mercantilism" refers to the first relatively organized school of thinking on international commerce, which developed in Europe during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. 

At around this time, pamphlets started appearing on economic topics, notably in England, and focusing on commerce. While a wide range of opinions is presented, there are a few recurring themes throughout the relevant literature. 

A common theme in the writings of mercantilists of the time was that a positive trade balance should be a primary goal of international commerce. The trade balance is considered "favorable" when the value of exports is higher than the value of imports. 

Profitability in commerce with a particular nation or area was measured by the amount of gold and other valuables added to the country's coffers as a consequence of exports exceeding imports. 

The extent to which mercantilists equated the accumulation of precious metals with gains in national prosperity was subsequently questioned by academics. Exports were seen positively by mercantilists, while imports were seen negatively.

However, the commodity mix of trade was cause for worry even if the balance of work itself was not. Raw material exports (to be used by foreign manufacturers) were negative, while manufactured product imports were positive. 

Processing and adding value to raw materials were thought to generate better employment opportunities than just extraction or primary production of essential goods, so these activities were ranked higher. 

This ranking was also based on establishing industries that bolster the economy and the national defense.

Navigating Trading

No matter how much they depend on expert advisors (EAs) or algorithms and modeling, most traders would say that trading is more of an art than a science. The constant flux and response of the market are contributing factors. 

That implies that as traders, we need to be able to adjust to new circumstances and conditions and attempt to "beat the market" or at least place our bets on the current state of affairs. 

Since there is no one trading method, there is ultimately no correct approach. Instead, there are many different ways to approach trading, but there are also specific universal strategies everyone can use to become more successful. 

According to mainstream economic theory, rising living standards fuel economic expansion, spurring more commerce. However, the actual data supporting such a connection is often lacking. 

By analyzing the elements that affect 'trade efficiency,' we want to understand this connection better. 

Trade Efficiency Rules

As per the results, examples may highlight many different types of historical events of Trade policies and efficiency Rules. For instance, since WWII ended, reforms have significantly lowered government-imposed trade obstacles. 

However, some issues need to be discussed: 

  1. Non-uniform rules: Domestic industry protection rules are unique. Some industries (like agricultural and apparel) and nation categories (like less developed countries) have much higher tariffs than others. 
  2. Regulations: While some nations have laws that actively encourage international investment and competition in the service industry, others have enacted strict rules on foreign firms looking to enter their markets. 
  3. Restriction on trade: In addition, trade restrictions disproportionately impact some nations. To make matters worse, industrialized nations generally shield their low-skill, labor-intensive exports from less developed countries. 

It has been stated that the United States receives roughly 15 cents in tariff money for every dollar of imports from Bangladesh. Still, the same amount of goods imported from major western European nations only brings in about one cent in tariff revenue. 

Yet, the duties on a particular item from Bangladesh are the same as or lower than the levies on a comparable import from western Europe. 

However extreme the United States tariffs on Bangladeshi goods may be, World Bank economists have determined that exporters from low-income countries face hurdles on average half times more extensive than those imposed by the exports of major industrialized nations.

Researched and Authored by Antra Sharma | LinkedIn

Reviewed & Edited by Ankit Sinha LinkedIn

Free Resources

To continue learning and advancing your career, check out these additional helpful WSO resources: